JOHN
O. McGINNIS
PROFESSOR OF LAW
BENJAMIN N. CARDOZO SCHOOL OF LAW,
YESHIVA UNIVERSITY
THE
STATE OF FEDERALISM
Thank
you for the opportunity to testify about federalism--the cornerstone of our
Constitution. I will first show how constitutional federalism provided the
greatest charter for liberty, wealth creation, and community in political
history. Second, I will outline
the sad decline of federalism in the twentieth century.
Third, I will offer some thoughts on reviving federalism so that it
once again will promote freedom, economic growth, and social solidarity.
Federalism was the Framers' most important contribution to solving the greatest dilemma of political theory. A government needs to be powerful enough to protect liberty and property, but a government sufficiently powerful to accomplish this end is also powerful enough to oppress the liberty of its citizens and expropriate their wealth.[i] Democracy does not dissolve this dilemma: an elected ruling coalition may tax and regulate for the benefit of its members rather than in the public interest. Indeed, in a democracy concentrated groups of citizens, called factions by James Madison and special interests today, possess peculiar leverage to obtain regulation and spending for their private benefit. The resulting excessive taxation and regulation are social evils that both restrict the individual pursuit of happiness and reduce the wealth of the whole nation.
Federalism was the Framers= primary way of assuring that government would act only in the public interest. The happy paradox of federalism is that two
interlocking governments can lead to less and better governance than a
unitary state. The key to the
structure is to use each level of government to constrain the other.
In the original Constitution the states brought the federal government
into being but strictly constrained its authority by granting it only certain
enumerated powers. For the
Framers, the essential domestic function of the national government was
limited to sustaining a free trade zone to facilitate the exchange of goods
and services among the former colonies and to provide for a common currency.
So circumscribed, the national government posed little threat to
liberties and wealth.
The Constitution left the rest of domestic regulation to the states. Although the states were thus repositories of enormous and potentially tyrannical powers, the free movement of goods and people among them restrained their ability to use their power to oppress the liberty or extract wealth from their citizens. If the states exercised their power unwisely free citizens could take themselves or their capital elsewhere.[ii] Thus the federal government was restrained by the strictly enumerated powers of the Constitution and the states were restrained by the competition that the federal government maintained through keeping open the avenues of trade and investment.[iii]
Because
of the limits the Constitution placed on regulation and spending for private
interests, economists today have explained that the original constitutional
design of a federalist free trading system was at the heart of the steady
growth of the United States that allowed it to become an economic superpower
by the beginning of the twentieth century.[iv]
Federalism was thus a large part of what made the Constitution the most
wealth producing document in human history.
Federalism not only limits government but also improves the
actions government necessarily must undertake.
The first way it does this is to create a marketplace for governments.
By putting state governments in competition with one another it forces
them to innovate in the way they deliver public goods--i.e. goods that the
market and the family cannot provide. Because
of this competition, useful innovations in governance are readily copied.
Federalism created a Alaboratory of democracy@ where the successful experiments of yesterday became the sound public
policy of tomorrow.
Second, federalism improved government decisions by pushing
them closer to the people they affect. Groups
of individuals may have different preferences for public goods.
Thus human happiness will be enhanced by letting the smallest feasible
unit of government deliver the
public good in question. Federalism
is the necessary beginning of this principle, called subsidiarity, but not the
end of it. Just as federalism
should force the national government to devolve appropriate decisions to the
states, so too should state constitutions force states to devolve appropriate
decisions to their localities.
Third,
federalism increases civic responsibility.
Political scientists have frequently noted that in large governments
citizens behave strategically,
making it harder to gain agreement on the public goods that will improve the
community. Federalism tempers
strategic behavior and substitutes in its place the genuine concern of one
citizen for another. As Adam
Smith noted, the spirit of genuine benevolence is more likely to operate at a
shorter distance.[v]
The resulting fellow feeling facilitates sound and harmonious public
policy.
Despite these enormous advantages, federalism has one important possible disadvantage. By multiplying the number of governments it permits officials to avoid accountability by making it harder for the public to determine which set of officials is responsible for a given governmental action. The strict enumeration of powers in the original Constitution, however, made it easier for citizens to hold state and federal official accountable for what they did in their respective spheres.
Unfortunately,
today the Framers=
blueprint for good government has faded.
By the early part of this century pressure had developed for a more
centralized structure of governance. The
Sixteenth Amendment permitting a federal income tax removed a major constraint
on the federal government by giving it access to almost unlimited revenues.
The Seventeenth Amendment terminating the election of Senators by state
legislators stripped the states of their principal institutional protectors in
Congress.
In
the 1930s the Supreme Court weakened federalism still further.
It eliminated the remaining constitutional limitations that prevented
the federal government from directly regulating manufacturing, thereby gravely
weakening regulatory competition among the states and centralizing power in
Washington. The Court also
abandoned its effort to limit Congress=s
spending power, essentially giving the federal government plenary spending
authority.
The dissolution of the limitations on government embodied in federalism has had dramatic and unfortunate consequences. First, the federal government now spends domestically seventeen times the percent of Gross National Product as it did at the beginning of this century when federalism was strong. Without the limitations of federalism, the federal government has also imposed far more regulations on our enterprises, both large and small, than it did at height of federalism. Moreover, the marketplace for government among the states works less well because state regulatory and spending programs have relatively small effects compared to those of the federal government.
Thus, because of federalism=s decline, our governments, both state and federal, spend less efficiently and tax and regulate more than they would in a system restrained by constitutional federalism. As a result, our more centralized state hinders economic growth. Less competition among the states has also led to less innovation in solving our social problems.
But
even worse are the losses to our civic life.
Because a more centralized system has made government less constrained
and less close to the people,
citizens have become more suspicious--in some cases cynical--of government.
Without the constraints of federalism it is easier for interest groups
to obtain spending or regulatory transfers for themselves at the expense of
others. Such a regime encourages
citizens to see one another either as potential targets (of expropriation and
taxation) or as threats (to their opportunities and wealth). Thus, the decline
of constitutional federalism has divided citizens, embittering our political
life. If
the evisceration of the constraints on the national
government has robbed our constitutional system of federalism=s
many virtues, it has also exacerbated its potential flaw--the reduction of
accountability for government officials.
Since the responsibilities of the state and federal government are no
longer distinct, it has become easier for federal official to avoid blame
for the costs of government actions.
For instance, Congress can impose mandates on the states, forcing
states and their localities to spend their own money on federal objectives.
Thus
federalism today is but a shadow of the Framers=
structure. I now turn to the
steps that are needed to reinvigorate it. The Court and Congress have been
making some progress in creating as much governmental accountability as
possible within the remaining
structures of federalism. Recently,
in New York v. United States, the Court held that the federal
government cannot order the state legislature to pass state laws.[vi]
The decision was based in part on the Court=s
view that federal commandeering of state legislatures would detract from
accountability, because citizens would have more difficulty in knowing whether
to attribute the regulation of their liberty to the state or federal
government. In Printz v.
United States, the Court expanded this holding to forbid the federal
government from commandeering state officials, thus requiring the federal
government to accept the responsibility for enforcing its own policies.[vii]
Congress has also responded to the need for greater accountability with the Unfunded Mandate Reform Act of 1995.[viii] The Act is very complex but its core feature is to require separate votes before Congress imposes new federal mandates that require the states to spend their own money. This legislation could be improved by requiring Congress to undertake the same procedure before renewing old mandates. Nevertheless it represents a useful first step for promoting accountability in this area.
The Government Partnership Act of 1999, a draft bill of Chairman Thompson, is an even more important step in restoring accountability. The bill would require Congress to provide reasons in a legislative report for its decision to preempt state law. Failure to provide such reasons would make the preempting legislation subject to a point of order. Second, the bill would declare that no legislation or regulation would preempt state law, unless it expressly so stated or if it conflicted with state law. Finally, the bill would require agencies to undertake a federalism assessment before they preempt state law. This is excellent legislation because it would force the federal government, both legislative and executive, to deliberate before preempting and preempt directly when it preempts at all. Such deliberation and clarity are hallmarks of government accountability.
This
draft bill also draws support for its rule of construction and procedural
requirements for deliberation from Garcia v. San
Antonio Metropolitan Transit Authority.[ix]
In that case the Supreme Court rejected the argument that the Tenth
Amendment prohibited federal minimum wage requirements from being applied to
state transit operations. The Court's core holding is that Congress' power to
impose its will on the states should be limited not by ad hoc judicial
determinations balancing state and federal interests under the Tenth Amendment
but by the states= participation in the national political process through the voice of
its elected representatives. But
states can participate in the national political process only if they know how
the federal government is affecting
their interests. Thus, by
requiring Congress to announce publicly its intention to preempt, the
Government Partnership Act helps secure more protection for the states.
Preemption that is not express also conflicts with the spirit of Garcia, because such preemption allows state law to be displaced indirectly by the inferences of an unelected federal judiciary. Federal accountability can be enforced only if the legislators elected from the several states are themselves required to displace state law. The abolition of non-express forms of preemption would thus mitigate the lack of legislative accountability that remains federalism=s chief potential flaw.
It
is a much harder task, however, to restore federalism=s
virtues--its hydraulic pressure for liberty and social solidarity. Only
through substantive restraints on the federal government will
states and localities once again become the main repositories of
policymaking that thrives through competition. Unless the federal government is constrained constitutionally
from spending and regulating, interest groups will bypass the states and
obtain spending and regulation on their behalf from the federal government.
One-stop shopping is not only easier, but it avoids the competitive
pressures that inhibit states from adopting special interest legislation.
Unfortunately,
because of precedent the Supreme Court is unlikely to restore the original
limitations on federal regulation and spending.
A very large number of federal programs now depend on national
legislature powers the Framers could not have imagined.
In the Tempting of America Judge Robert Bork, hardly a friend of
the New Deal's transformation of the Constitution, states bluntly that to
overrule the Court's expansion of the enumerated powers would be
"overturn much of modern government and plunge us into chaos." [x]
But members of Congress need not wait for the Court to restore federalism: they can do it themselves without upsetting current programs. Chairman Thompson took up that challenge when he proposed codifying President Reagan=s executive order on federalism, E.O. 12612. That order required agencies to undertake a federalism assessment before engaging in new regulation. The federalism assessment required agencies, inter alia, to state their constitutional authority for any federal action and demonstrate that the problem they were addressing was national rather than local in scope. Codification would prevent these laudable restraints on federal action from being repealed. It would improve agency compliance which, according to a recent draft GAO report, has been shockingly poor.
Nevertheless, while such a codification would be wholly
salutary (particularly if the legislation contained provisions for judicial
review), it would still not completely restore
constitutional federalism. For
instance, the requirement that the executive branch find constitutional
authority for its actions will in most cases be readily satisfied through the
expanded powers the Court has given the federal government.
Moreover, Congress itself could still invade the province of the
states.
Congress has also been considering proposals that would revive constitutional federalism more fully. In my view, the most promising are constitutional supermajority rules that would constrain the federal government=s spending ability. The Balanced Budget Amendment was an example of this approach: it required a supermajority to raise the national debt. Just last month the House considered an amendment which would have required a two-thirds majority to raise taxes. Since either taxes or debt can be used to support more federal spending these amendments should be combined to create an effective check on the national government. As Professor Michael Rappaport and I have suggested, supermajority requirements applied directly to spending levels and to the creation of new entitlements would be simpler and more effective at reviving federalism than supermajority requirements applied to taxes and spending.[xi]
By
forcing individuals to go to their states for additional spending and new
entitlements, such an amendment would once again restore the benefits of the
constitutional federalism of the Framers.
States would be reinvigorated as the primary locus of innovation in
public spending. The wisdom of
their decisions would again be tested by vigorous competition.
Yet a federalism reanimated by such supermajority rules on federal
spending would still permit Congress to increase spending levels and create
new entitlements when its action reflected a very broad national consensus.
For similar reasons, a constitutional amendment reviving the nondelegation doctrine and preventing Congress from delegating excessive regulatory authority to federal agencies would also reinvigorate federalism. The Framers bestowed national regulatory authority on the legislature rather than on the executive precisely because they knew that it would be difficult to obtain from that diverse body the consensus necessary to encroach on liberty and property. Forcing Congress itself to enact regulatory programs will have the advantage of naturally limiting the yearly agenda of possible national intrusions.[xii] Individuals thus would look to their states in the first instance to obtain government regulations. Yet Congress would remain available to address truly national problems if it could obtain the consensus to pass a determinate set of regulations rather than shift responsibility for its solution to federal agencies.
Of
course, constitutional amendments may take a long time to pass.
In the interim appropriate supermajority rules for spending, taxes, and
debt can be adopted by legislative rule.[xiii]
Statutory restraints on excessive federal regulation would also begin
to force individuals to look more to their states.
Indeed, it is important to remember that besides their other virtues
regulatory reform measures always aid federalism.
In restricting the scope of federal regulation, they vitalize the
states in the precise areas in which federal action has been prohibited or
made more difficult.
In recommending such measures, I recognize that I am asking members of this Committee and all members of Congress to give up power. I also recognize that the revival of constitutional federalism will necessarily sometimes prevent national legislators from passing legislation that they believe to be in the public interest. But constitutional government itself rests on the notion that public interest is served in the long run by maintenance of structures that through their very constraints improve governmental action. Federalism is the most important of these structures. Its preservation is thus worthy of our attention and sacrifice.
Endnotes
[i].
Barry Weingast, The Economic Role of Political Institutions:
Market Preserving Federalism and Economic Development, 11 Econ. J.L. Econ. Org. 1, 1 (1995).
[ii].
Of course, an essential flaw in the original Constitution was its
failure to make all citizens free--a precondition for constitutional
federalism to work for everyone. The
Thirteenth, Fourteenth, and Fifteenth Amendments as well as federal
legislation to enforce their promise were essential if the benefits of
constitutional federalism were to be made available to all Americans.
[iii].
Some have argued that competition among the states nevertheless has a
substantial cost, because it encourages a race to the bottom in such matters
as environmental regulation. I
cannot agree, because I do not believe there will generally be a race to the
bottom. Take for instance the
case of environmental pollution. The
best recent economic models suggest that where the jurisdictions do not
export their pollution (i.e. where there are no substantial spillover
effects beyond the jurisdiction) they are likely to provide an appropriate
level of regulation for their own citizens even when they are competing to
attract businesses from other jurisdictions.
The practical point is that people want to work in jurisdictions with
a pleasant environment. The simplified essence of the theory is that
jurisdictional competition means that the cost of environmental regulations
will be reflected directly in lost
wages. This connection will be
conducive to setting the level of regulation at a point where the marginal
cost of a unit of regulation equals the marginal benefit for individuals
within that jurisdiction. For an excellent discussion of these models, see Richard L.
Revesz, Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the ARace
to the Bottom Rationale@
in Environmental Regulation,
67 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1210
(1992). Where there are
environmental spillover effects among jurisdictions, the federal government
would have had authority to address them under even under the original
meaning of the Commerce Clause.
[iv].
Weingast, supra, at 24-28.
[v].
Michael W. McConnell, Federalism: Evaluating the Framers=
Design, 54 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1484, 1493 (1987) (quoting Adam Smith).
[vi].
New York v. United States, 505 U.S. 120 (1992).
[viii].
Pub. L. No. 104-4 (March 22, 1995).
[ix].
Garcia v. Antonio Metropolitan Transit Authority, 469 U.S. 528
(1985).
[x].
Robert H. Bork, The Tempting of
America 159 (1990). To be
sure, the Court has made some modest steps in reviving the enumerated
powers. Recently in United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549 (1995), the Court held that Congress does not have the authority to regulate
activity that is neither commercial nor crosses state lines.
Because of fifty years of precedent, however, we can not expect the
Court to restore the strict limitations on federal regulatory and spending
authority.
[xi].
John O. McGinnis & Michael B. Rappaport, Supermajority Rules
as a Constitutional Solution, 40 Wm.
& My. L. Rev. 365 (1999).
[xii].
For further discussion of the reasons to restore the nondelegation doctrine,
see Marci A. Hamilton, Representation and Nondelegation: Back to Basics, 20
Cardozo L. Rev. 807 (1999).
[xiii].The House of Representatives has already adopted a supermajority rule for taxes. Such rules represent a constitutional use of each House=s authority to set its own rules. See John O. McGinnis & Michael B. Rappaport, The Constitutionality of Legislative Supermajority Requirements: A Defense, 105 Yale L. J. 483 (1995).
This home page was created and
is maintained by the Senate Governmental Affairs Committee.
Questions or comments can be sent to: webmaster@govt-aff.senate.gov